THE BLOG

Why Land Is A Barrier Between Plough And Plate

01/03/2017 12:05 PM IST | Updated 24/03/2017 1:37 PM IST

The increasing fragmentation of cultivated land in most parts of India makes it difficult to build supply chains of produce from farm gates to end consumers in an efficient and viable manner.

Mallika Viegas
The food supply chain from farms remains weak in India

By Sanjiv Phansalkar*

In the past decade or so, there has been frequent talk about "plough to plate" in Indian agriculture. The allegory is meant to represent addressing the issues in the entire value chain that has farm production of food on one end and the final consumer at the other. Doing so is expected to eliminate inefficiencies and waste in the system and result in improved incomes for the farmers as well as enhanced value for the consumer.

To obtain a single tonne of fresh peas in Madhya Pradesh, a processor may have to engage with 15-20 farmers...

For a tiny, if not microscopic, section of producers in some select pockets of the country, this dream has been approximated. However, for a huge bulk of producers, this dream is elusive. It is also undeniable that land and affiliation to it comes in the way. This issue of effective and beneficial integration of small producers of farm produce in the food markets has received quite some attention in recent times. There are issues in the production systems as well as in the large variability in time, space and taste of consumers, the proverbial kings of the markets.

The question of land

Typical operational holdings are small, often under a hectare. These holdings too may not be in a single contiguous patch of land, but scattered in four or five smaller parts. Land consolidation has occurred only in the irrigated alluvial Indo-Gangetic basin areas of Western Uttar Pradesh, Haryana, and Punjab. In these pockets, even with the subdivision of property over generations, the average plot sizes remain reasonably large, often closer to a hectare.

In most other regions, however, because of spatial diversification to partially offset weather or nature-induced risk and partially as a result of subdivision of land over generations, average plot sizes have fallen drastically. The smallest average plot sizes are in very populous states such as West Bengal or Bihar. It may be argued that even so, all the farmers in a contiguous compact area can grow a pre-decided crop so that lot size will rise and of the produce will become somewhat more homogeneous.

The number of transactions for the same volume is much higher in the Indian farm sector than most developed countries. Quality variations are much higher too...

But this does not happen since small plots are owned by autonomous smallholder farmers. They decide independently of each other and in response to their own family conditions and opportunity sets. Each of them tries to diversify his crop and activity mix—both to meet a wider range of his economic needs and to reap the advantage of the incomplete correlation between variation in crop incomes.

As a combined result of these two factors, for any market operator interested in engaging in the processing of a food crop, operations become tough. To obtain 10 tonnes of wheat in Punjab, a market operator may have to engage with just one farmer. But to obtain a single tonne of fresh peas in Madhya Pradesh, a processor may have to engage with 15-20 farmers spread over a much wider area than a single farm. Several consequences follow.

Transaction costs

The number of transactions for the same volume is much higher in the Indian farm sector than most developed countries. Quality variations are much higher too, as are coordination costs on a per unit basis. Efforts to harmonise growing practices across farmers, to change agronomy, and to introduce innovations therefore become more expensive in Indian agriculture. Moral hazard has a greater chance of affecting contracts and the cost of monitoring and contract enforcement high.

The issues arising out of the consumer side are well known. I was told by a marketer that there are 16 types of wheat and nine types of wheat flour in demand and one of his competitive advantages is in matching the right wheat for processing the flour needed in a specific region. Consumer tastes and preferences in fresh produce vary even more sharply and by occasion and time of the year. Matching these variations with a production schedule as characterised above is so tough that no one has seriously even attempted it.

A large proportion of FPOs are organisational equivalents of severe malnutrition and stunting. This happens due to peculiar legal regulations...

It can perhaps be said that market is and will remain what it is and it is better to make adjustments in the production systems if better alignment and value accretion is sought. This calls for consolidation. In the absence of any meaningful possibility of land consolidation and with perennial atomisation of producers, it calls for virtual consolidation. This could be in the form of harmonising production efforts via a farmer producer organisation (FPO) that can credibly act on their behalf or of short and medium term leasing so that decision making can be centralised; or contract farming.

Meaningful business

The first solution has been pushed by many, including the World Bank, but has made hardly any dent. A large proportion of FPOs are organisational equivalents of severe malnutrition and stunting. This happens due to peculiar legal regulations: only producers can have equity in these. Since producers are small and poor, they can barely contribute. That means that the FPO has little owned funds and remains impeded from doing any meaningful business.

The second solution of short- or medium-term leasing has not been seriously tried out on a formal and large enough scale. A current Bill under consideration of Parliament could pave the way for this to come about. Finally, there is the possibility of contract farming. This would become possible when market players see large enough business in fresh farm produce. Feeble attempts for contract farming have started for a few commodities like potato, but the scale is too small.

Thus, land does indeed come in between the plough and the plate and we are struggling to remove it from retarding the growth of the farm sector.

Sanjiv Phansalkar is Programme Director at Tata Trusts. He was earlier a faculty member at the Institute of Rural Management Anand (IRMA). Phansalkar is a fellow of the Indian Institute of Management (IIM) Ahmedabad.

This article was first published on VillageSquare.in, a public-interest communications platform focused on rural India.

More On This Topic

SPONSORED BY THE LIVE, LOVE, LAUGH FOUNDATION